Democracy Gone Astray

Democracy, being a human construct, needs to be thought of as directionality rather than an object. As such, to understand it requires not so much a description of existing structures and/or other related phenomena but a declaration of intentionality.
This blog aims at creating labeled lists of published infringements of such intentionality, of points in time where democracy strays from its intended directionality. In addition to outright infringements, this blog also collects important contemporary information and/or discussions that impact our socio-political landscape.

All the posts here were published in the electronic media – main-stream as well as fringe, and maintain links to the original texts.

[NOTE: Due to changes I haven't caught on time in the blogging software, all of the 'Original Article' links were nullified between September 11, 2012 and December 11, 2012. My apologies.]

Wednesday, September 14, 2011

Useless User Fees Punish the Poor

Making patients pay won't make our health system more affordable or accessible.


Here it comes again – an idea that surfaces regularly in Canadian health-care debates and seems to hold sway with those who advocate common-sense principles: user fees.

Some people think that charging patients when they use the health system would help control health-care costs and ensure that people are getting the care they need and are not overusing the system. Others believe that user fees would bring in much-needed revenue.

Unfortunately, the evidence doesn’t support these aspirations. Research to date suggests two good reasons patient-financed health care doesn’t make sense.

First, user fees discourage patients from seeking both necessary and unnecessary care. This is often penny wise and pound foolish.

Some claim that user fees are benign because they discourage only frivolous use. But that assumes that most people have the expert knowledge required to know what care is needed. A host of studies have found the opposite to be true. One U.S. study published in the New England Journal of Medicine involving fairly healthy adults showed that user fees led to a 20-per-cent increase in risk of death for people with high blood pressure because people were less likely to see a doctor and get their blood pressure under control.

The same thing happened in Canada in 1996, when Quebec began requiring patients to pay part of the cost of all drugs purchased. According to a study in the Journal of the American Medical Association, patients reduced their use of less-essential drugs and essential drugs, often resulting in serious negative effects on their health and increased emergency-department visits.



Does preserving Canada's public health system mean accepting certain fundamental changes? Click here to read one expert's position.



The evidence shows that, faced with user fees, people often do without preventative care and chronic-disease management. User fees mean we have to decide whether symptoms warrant medical attention. For example, when a child has a fever, most parents don’t know whether it’s the flu or the onset of meningitis. Do we really want parents to make the decision of whether to take their child to the doctor on the basis of whether the user fee will leave enough money to pay the rent?

This leads to the second finding.

Health care financed by patients does not save money. It may transfer costs from third-party payers to patients, but the total cost is often higher. Indeed, this helps explain the contradictory beliefs noted above – if user fees bring in new revenue, they cannot simultaneously control costs.

One reason for this relates to what happens to resources not used by those discouraged from seeking care. While user fees sometimes discourage sick people from filling hospital beds or booking doctors’ appointments, research shows that these freed-up resources are not closed down. Instead, they often end up providing people who can more easily afford the user fees with care that they may not need. That is, user fees may – ironically – encourage unnecessary or marginally useful care in order to make sure the physicians and hospital beds available stay busy.

Individual patients also have less ability to negotiate prices, particularly when they are very ill. In other words, it may cost them more to buy the same.

Let’s face it: Most people don’t want a heart transplant or a hip replacement just because those services are free. Doctors, not patients, determine who gets access to most health-care treatments. So what do user fees really discourage? They discourage the frugal and the poor from getting the care they really need.



How can we save health care without going broke? Read about it here.



When the patient pays, buying insurance is typically part of the package. Unfortunately, that package can change rapidly. A recent report from the U.S.-based Commonwealth Fund describes sharp rises in premiums for employer-sponsored family plans between 2003 and 2009, with premiums increasing more than three times faster than median incomes. Deductibles also rose nearly 80 per cent over this period. And it is precisely the sickest – those who need the most care – who have the greatest trouble finding an insurance company willing to cover them.

One type of user-fee system that might make sense was recently proposed in Europe: Add user fees to low-value services and eliminate them from high-value services. But that takes a lot of work up front to figure out what medical care works and what doesn’t – and for whom – and to convince patients and providers that these decisions are accurate. No one has yet tried this approach.

The scientific evidence supporting publicly financed care is long and strong. So why do discredited ideas like user fees keep coming back?

Economist Robert Evans and his colleagues have examined this issue, and refer to user fees and related ideas as “zombies”: These ideas have been killed off repeatedly by the scientific evidence, but, somehow, they keep bouncing back to life to wreak havoc with our public policy.

Origin
Source: the Mark 

No comments:

Post a Comment